Archive for the ‘Decentralization’ Category

Governance system for local governments – Part 1 – Profit by Pakistan Today

Why local government? The World Bank in its 1997 report asserts that governments are more effective when they listen to businesses and citizens, and work in partnership with them in deciding and implementing policy. Where governments lack mechanisms to listen, they are not responsive to peoples interests.

The devolution of authority to local tiers of government and decentralization can bring in representation of local business and citizens interests. The visibility of the results achieved by the resources deployed in a specific geographic area maintains pressure on government functionaries. Publicprivate partnerships. including NGOpublic partnerships have proved to be effective tools in fostering good governance.

The World Development Report (WDR 2004) has argued that the accountability of governments to local communities and marginalized social groups will increase by assigning service delivery functions to politicians who are closer to the people and make them electorally accountable.

The 1973 constitution did specify only two tiers of government federal and provincial. It is only after the 18th Amendment in 2010 that a new clause Article 140A was introduced which states that Each province shall, by law, establish a local government system and devolve political, administrative and financial responsibility and authority to the elected representatives of the local governments.

The Supreme court has asserted and directed the holding of elections of local governments on several occasions. Unfortunately, unlike the detailed distribution of powers between the federal and the provincial governments clearly defined in the constitution, there is no such provision for local governments. This vagueness and ambiguity has been used by the provincial governments which have been struggling to come to some reasonable piece of legislation since 2010 on the functions and powers of this tier.

Logically, once the provincial governments were devolved, adequate powers accompanied by sufficient financial allocations out of the divisible tax pool and grants from the federal government there should have been similar decentralization and delegation to the local governments. How is it possible for Punjab, with a population of 110 million people and 36 districts covering an area of 205000 sq km, to respond to the disparate needs of citizens in the delivery of essential services? DG Khan and Faisalabad, for example, have very different requirements and a uniform one-shoe-fits-all approach that is the characteristic of an overcentralized system wont simply work.

The present culture of concentrating authority in power centres at Islamabad, Lahore, Karachi, Peshawar and Quetta has not only alienated the population living in the peripheries, but reduced its productive potential also and to no small extent. It is little surprise then that our research found 80 districts whose ordinary citizens are living in miserable conditions, according to the Deprivation Index, and remain almost criminally starved of their most basic needs.

The political parties that introduced this article in the constitution do not realize that meaningful empowerment of communities through decentralization and delegation of authority, in which the local government system plays a crucial role would in the long run promote greater trust, cohesion and harmony in our society and ensure access to basic public services in an efficient and equitable manner. These outcomes will not only help mobilize additional resources at the local level but also improve the efficiency of resource utilization.

The present state of disaffection and discontentment with the government would also be mitigated if public goods and services of everyday use to the citizens become available to them at the grassroots level. Local communities know their problems and their solutions much better than anybody else. It has also been found that for direct delivery by the government, the transfer of responsibility for these services to lower tiers of governance improves access by the poor.

Local government management of schools and hospitals involving communities and demand-side subsidies to the poor, monitored and under the oversight of government result in a favourable outcome in education and health. As these political parties will also contest elections, they will be represented at that tier of government too. Thus, the credit for citizen satisfaction, efficient allocation of resources and better access to essential services would go to the political parties themselves.

However, the myopic and self-centred approach adopted by all major political parties and resistance to empowerment and strengthening local governments is highly incomprehensible as in actual fact it simply entails the transfer of power from the provincial and national legislators and the ministers to the locally elected nazims or mayors of the districts. Those seeking to preserve their status, clout and influence should opt for local nazim positions rather than becoming MPAs or MNAs.

The 2001-2009 period: It would be useful to make an objective assessment of the local government system that existed in Pakistan between 2001 and 2009. There were many flaws in the 2001 system, including the fact that the functions of law and order, revenue records, and land administration and disaster management should have remained with neutral civil servants and not transferred to the nazims. In that event, the offices of the deputy/assistant commissioner should not have been abolished, thereby diluting the writ of the state.

The executive authority of the newly created post of district coordination officer DCO was diluted as magisterial powers were taken away from him or her although s/he was expected to perform duties relating to maintenance of law and order, removal of encroachments, price controls, and the like. As the powers of recruitment, transfers, postings, and disciplinary actions continued to remain vested in the provincial departments, the diarchy proved to be fatal for the effective functioning of the devolved departments.

The gap between law and actual practice remained wide to the detriment of the public at large. Corruption at the district government level could not be contained given the inadequate supervisory arrangements evolved by the provincial governments. The provincial secretaries retained considerable administrative authority over the district bureaucrats and used these powers to undercut the efficacy of the elective nazims. A tripartite confrontational mode in which the provincial ministers and secretaries aligned themselves against the district nazims was responsible for most of the practical difficulties faced by the citizens in access to services.

The degree of fiscal decentralization remained limited because the districts continued to depend upon the province for resources, didnt have the powers to collect new taxes, and didnt have the capacity to levy service or user charges. On the expenditure side, the fixed and growing expense of salaries, wages, and allowances paid to the staff devolved to the district governments (although they continue to be provincial servants) did not leave much surplus for either maintenance, operational, and development expenditure.

Over 90 per cent of expenditure of local governments was financed by transfers from the provincial governments. Lack of enhancement in local fiscal powers was a major weakness in the process of fiscal decentralization.

The share of local governments in the provincial allocable pool was about 40 per cent but their share in total public expenditure was only 13 per cent. Resource mobilization at the provincial and local levels remained substantially under-exploited. Land revenue accounted for less than one per cent of the agricultural income while the effective rate of property taxation of rental incomes was about five per cent as opposed to the statutory rate of 20 per cent or more.

The fragmentation of development projects into small schemes catered to the narrow interests of the local communities without any sense of priority, linkages, or widespread coverage.

Ideally, the transfer of resources from urban to rural areas should be a welcome move but such a transfer in the absence of a district-wide plan without specifying the goals to be achieved and assessing the cost-benefit of the approved schemes can be counterproductive. Urban-rural integration did not recognize or cater to the needs of growing urbanization.

Hasnain concludes on the basis of his study that in order to keep his voters happy, the district nazim would have very little choice but to acquiesce to the pressures exerted by the union and tehsil Nazims to allocate resources equally. The difference between equal and equitable distribution of resources should be understood as it is at the crux of the problem.

Under an equal distribution scheme there is no clear relationship between the needs of the community and the intended interventions. Rich and poor communities will receive the same amount irrespective of the intensity of their need. Equitable distribution takes into account the differences in the initial endowments and conditions of the intended beneficiaries. Those who are poor, marginalized, live in remote or geographically disadvantaged areas and cannot earn decent incomes on their own should receive higher allocations than those who are better off. Public resources thus supplement the private incomes of the poor to help out of poverty.

Two innovative features of the 2001 system are worth mentioning. The reservation of one-third seats for women and others for peasants, workers, minorities, the marginalized classes of our society, was an extremely commendable step. Similarly, the integration of the rural and urban administrative units at the tehsil level would have allowed the rural areas to benefit equally from the larger envelope of pooled resources available to the Tehsil Council. Even if the underlying patron-client relationship persists, the scope for inclusion of clients who were traditionally denied access under a MNA/MPA centred system, will be much wider under a decentralized and devolved system.

However, despite these flaws, empirical studies and surveys point to the net positive achievements of the local government system. The Social Audit Survey 2009-10 of 12,000 households drawn from 21 districts in all four provinces found that 56 per cent favoured the continuation of the local government system with high proportions in Punjab and Sindh. The level of satisfaction with the union councils was 33.8 per cent but the situation regarding support and social acceptability of womens participation seemed to have improved. Sixty per cent of female union councilors were of the view that people in their constituencies were happy with them.

The satisfaction levels of households with various public services varied but by 2009-10 satisfaction with roads, sewerage and sanitation, garbage disposal, water supply, health and education had improved although in percentage terms only less than half of the households expressed satisfaction with the services. Public education, at 58 per cent, showed the highest level of satisfaction.

The Social Policy Development Centre (SPDC) carried out a survey of 12 districts in the four provinces and found that the rate of enhancement in literacy of the population and access to water supply and sanitation had perceptibly increased during the post-devolution period. However, there were no indications of any impact of devolution on health indicators. The process of devolution was beginning to contribute to a quicker improvement in enrolment at the primary level and literacy in Pakistan.

At a micro level, Cheema and Mohmand analyzed a dataset of 364 households in the rural tehsil of Jaranwala in Faisalabad District to gain some insights regarding the types of households which gain and lose through electoral decentralization and whether the change in the post-reform provision between different household types is equitable. The empirical results of their study showed that increased access to development funds and heightened mandates for union nazims have resulted in a significant increase in union level provisions within a short span of time. They further found that the increase in the post-reform provision in nazim villages is less elite-based as it encompasses small peasants, minority peasant biradaris, and non-agricultural castes.

Hasnain reports on the basis of a survey carried out in 2005 that over 60 per cent of the households stated that they would approach a union councilor or Nazim to resolve their problems in comparison to only 10 per cent who said they would approach members of the provincial or national assembly. This reflects the increase in accessibility of policymakers after devolution. A system in which bureaucrats control the development departments provides neither access nor accountability. Having a system of elected nazims and councilors who remain responsive to the needs of their citizens is better because these officials are liable to lose their offices if they do not fulfil their responsibilities and duties. The best one can do with a recalcitrant bureaucrat is to transfer him out of a particular district but that does not resolve the inherent problem of access to the poor.

Cheema, Khawaja and Qadir in their study found that three types of changes were brought about by the 2001 devolution. One, changes in the decision-making level of the service from provincial bureaucrats to district level bureaucracy. Two, changes in the decision-makers accountability from bureaucrats to elected representatives at the district level; and three, changes in the fiscal resources available to the service.

The education department, primary healthcare and the management of district and tehsil hospitals experienced a change of the first type, where the decisions previously made by the provincial secretariat and the provincial cabinet were transferred to the district nazim and executive district officers.

The municipal services provided by the local government, the rural development department, and the public health engineering departments of the provincial government became the sole functional responsibility of the tehsil municipal administration. This was a fundamental change because the power to allocate resources, prioritize projects, and deliver results moved away from 48 provincial departments to 6000 units of local government whereas prior to devolution, the deconcentrated provincial bureaucracy at the district level was accountable to their non-elected provincial secretariat. The 2001 devolution made them accountable to the elected heads of districts and tehsil governments. Under the previous system, the de-facto head of the district administration was the district commissioner who would report to the non-elected commissioner while after devolution he reported to the elected district nazim (mayor).

Their study also found that a rule-based fiscal transfer system between the provinces and the local governments was established under the 2001 Devolution Plan. Approximately 40 per cent of the provincial consolidated fund was distributed among local governments with due weightage given to backwardness in order to ensure some form of equity across districts in the allocation of development funds. The other innovation was that these budgetary transfers did not lapse at the end of the year but continued to be retained by the relevant local governments, providing for flexibility and presumably some improvement in the efficiency of resource allocation

Proposed governance system for local governments: In light of the experience of the 2001 LGO, let us now examine what needs to be done to avoid the weaknesses of the previous system and implement the spirit of Article 140A using political, administrative and financial dimensions of devolution.

The remainder of this piece will be published in next weeks issue.

Read this article:

Governance system for local governments - Part 1 - Profit by Pakistan Today

Bitcoin Spark’s ICO promises rewarding returns for Early Investors – Captain Altcoin

Home Journal Bitcoin Sparks ICO promises rewarding returns for Early Investors

Bitcoin Spark (BTCS), with its Initial Coin Offering (ICO) in full throttle, offers early investors the chance to be part of a promising venture. Bitcoin Sparks ICO is in the last stages of phase three at affordable pricing and enticing bonus, before rolling out phase four at an increased value but declined bonus offer. BTCS provides enticing returns for those who recognize its potential early on, and the phase three holders will realize a 560% ROI.

BTCS, a ticker for Bitcoin Spark, is a decentralized cryptocurrency project that seeks to revolutionize crypto mining and rewards distribution. This Bitcoin fork, built on Ethereum, is driven by an innovative concept, the Proof-Of-Process (PoP) consensus mechanism, aimed at enhancing security and scalability while maintaining decentralization. The project emphasizes decentralization by encouraging more validators to participate, bolstering network security. By combining unique approaches like the non-linear rewards system, BTCS plans to create a self-sustaining mining ecosystem that offers consistent profitability to miners.

Bitcoin Spark uses a smart combination of proof-of-work and proof-of-stake mechanisms, and a special algorithm, to ensure stability and fairness in distributing rewards. Miners need to solve hexadecimal hashes to earn rewards. While solving hexadecimal hashes wont be the primary way to earn, users need to stake on the network, similar to how Proof-Of-Stake blockchains work. However, the relationship between stake and earnings isnt linear. Unlike traditional systems that solely favor high computing power or large stakes, Bitcoin Sparks approach prevents imbalanced rewards based purely on monetary worth.

The network also requires users to contribute processing power to Bitcoin Sparks clients for remote computing tasks that demand high CPU or GPU usage. An exciting feature is that users can contribute processing power through an app in a secure virtual environment, setting Bitcoin Spark apart. BTCS provides miners with a user-friendly Bitcoin Spark application, enabling them to contribute their device processing power to the network and earn rewards.

Rewards are calculated based on a combination of the individual stake and the work performed as remote computing. The more work and stake provided, the higher the rewards but this relationship isnt linear. Higher emphasis is placed on work done to prioritize the revenue-generating product.

Bitcoin Spark caps users to contribute around 5 Teraflops of processing power before experiencing rewards reduction. This estimation may change over time based on total network output, client demand, remaining mining rewards, and total BTCS staked. The system will adapt with technological advancements to stay relevant.

Through its ICO and advanced technologies, Bitcoin Spark envisions a balanced and profitable environment for miners while contributing to the broader cryptocurrency landscape. BTCS rolled out phase one of its ICO at $1.50 and a 20% bonus, with phase one holders expecting an 800% ROI.

Phase two featured one BTCS at $1.75 and a 15% bonus, for an ROI of 657%. Imagine acquiring Bitcoin when its value was $1. The current phase three, which is running out fast, has one BTCS at $2.00 and a 12% bonus. Phase three holders expect 560% in ROI gains.

As evidenced above, Bitcoin Spark implements high rewards in the early ICO stages, rewarding in a big way the early investors. Early adopters enjoy an affordable BTCS price, which keeps increasing after each phase, and bonuses which diminish as phases progress. After the project launch in November, the early adopters will enjoy higher margins and will have earned impressive amounts in bonuses.

Bitcoin Sparks profitability is driven by a thoughtful blend of mechanisms that value both stake and active contribution, fostering a fair and lucrative environment for its participants. The reward structure is designed to prioritize revenue generation. The more work a user performs and the higher their stake, the greater their rewards, but this relationship follows a non-linear pattern.

This approach encourages participation by both large and small stakeholders, enhancing network security and decentralization. Apart from processing power rental, the BTCS ecosystem also introduces a new advertising concept where users can vote out adverts if inappropriate.

Read more on BTCS here:

Website|Buy BTCS

Disclaimer: We advise readers to do their own research before interacting with any featured companies. The information provided is not financial or legal advice. Neither CaptainAltcoin nor any third party recommends buying or selling any financial products. Investing in cryptoassets is high-risk; consider the potential for loss. CaptainAltcoin is not liable for any damages or losses from using or relying on this content.

CaptainAltcoin's writers and guest post authors may or may not have a vested interest in any of the mentioned projects and businesses. None of the content on CaptainAltcoin is investment advice nor is it a replacement for advice from a certified financial planner. The views expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official policy or position of CaptainAltcoin.com

Read more here:

Bitcoin Spark's ICO promises rewarding returns for Early Investors - Captain Altcoin

Ethereum MEV incentives limit decentralization new report shows – CryptoSlate

What is CryptoSlate Alpha?

A web3 membership designed to empower you with cutting-edge insights and knowledge. Learn more

Welcome! You are connected to CryptoSlate Alpha. To manage your wallet connection, click the button below.

If you don't have enough, buy ACS on the following exchanges:

Access Protocol is a web3 monetization paywall. When users stake ACS, they can access paywalled content. Learn more

Disclaimer: By choosing to lock your ACS tokens with CryptoSlate, you accept and recognize that you will be bound by the terms and conditions of your third-party digital wallet provider, as well as any applicable terms and conditions of the Access Foundation. CryptoSlate shall have no responsibility or liability with regard to the provision, access, use, locking, security, integrity, value, or legal status of your ACS Tokens or your digital wallet, including any losses associated with your ACS tokens. It is solely your responsibility to assume the risks associated with locking your ACS tokens with CryptoSlate. For more information, visit our terms page.

Go here to see the original:

Ethereum MEV incentives limit decentralization new report shows - CryptoSlate

How to decentralize a prover, according to an engineer who did it for fun – Blockworks

Andrew Milson, a senior software engineer at Immutable, recently submitted his own proof to StarkWares StarkNet verifier on Ethereum.

Generally speaking, a prover is a computational entity responsible for attesting that information is accurate without revealing its underlying data. Provers must create proofs that can be easily verified by a verifier.

The issue today is that many zero-knowledge (ZK) blockchain projects depend on one single, centralizedprover. In the event that node fails to submit proofs, transaction finality will be impacted.

But the process of decentralizing provers is no easy feat.

Milsons interest in STARKs is what started the entire ordeal, he told Blockworks.

When I found out they could be used to prove very large computations instantly in a small proof, I just lost my mind. It didnt even seem possible, and the mystery resulted in me becoming obsessed with figuring out how they worked, Milson said.

During this time, he built miniSTARK, a tool that enables you to prove the integrity of arbitrary computations using STARKs and also spent time learning about Cairo a STARK programming language.

Its simplicity is beautiful, and the fact that StarkNet is built on top of it strikes me as very strong, Milson said.

STARK verifiers are very similar in structure to their provers, Milson said.

Being able to see StarkWares verifier contracts on Ethereum essentially provided me with a blueprint that I was able to follow line by line, he said.

Milson began copying Solidity contracts into a foundry project and wrote tests for the verifyProof process, he said.

It was an iterative process that involved the following:

Each iteration, Id get slightly more lines of code passing until the whole test worked, Milson said. I used the passing proof and submitted it to Ethereum using Etherscanner. It was a real thrill once everything was submitted on-chain.

Milson believes that being able to submit his own prover is a step towards decentralization for StarkNet.

Teams in the community can start integrating the prover into their work which will bring a lot of scale and interesting use cases to the ecosystem, for example, onchain Gaming and ZKML, he said.

This sentiment is shared by Liron Hayman, the head of business development at Starkware.

This is a very important milestone towards decentralization of the Starknet tech stack. Andrew was able to develop his prover without viewing the code of StarkWares prover, Hayman told Blockworks. A mature decentralized blockchain like Starknet requires a vibrant community developing multiple implementations of each component. Andrews work is taking STARK technology to serious decentralization and by extension, towards fulfilling its potential.

Milson believes his work can also be viewed as an audit of StarkNets existing verifier and a testament to the security of the network.

I inspected every line of code and I couldnt find a bug which was honestly a bit disappointing considering how juicy StarkNets bug bounty program is, but really impressive on StarkWares behalf, Milson said.

Get the days top crypto news and insights delivered to your email every evening.Subscribe to Blockworks free newsletternow.

Want alpha sent directly to your inbox? Get degen trade ideas, governance updates, token performance, cant-miss tweets and more fromBlockworks Researchs Daily Debrief.

Cant wait? Get our news the fastest way possible.Join us on Telegramand follow us onGoogle News.

Original post:

How to decentralize a prover, according to an engineer who did it for fun - Blockworks

PayPal USD: Boon for Ethereum but not decentralization, says community – Cointelegraph

PayPals new Ethereum-based stablecoin, PYUSD, has been seen as bittersweet news for the crypto community.

While it could finally see Ethereum find its place in mainstream adoption, it could also spell trouble for decentralization and personal control of assets, warns the community.

The new stablecoin, PayPal USD, was launched on Aug. 7 and is issued by Paxos Trust Co. the firm behind Binance USD (BUSD). Its built on Ethereum and designed for digital payments and Web3, with the firm saying it will soon be available to United States customers.

The launch has been seen as a boon for Ethereum adoption. Ethereum bulls Anthony Sassano and Ryan Sean Adams believe the ERC-20 stablecoin will push the blockchain closer toward becoming the money layer of the internet.

The number of daily active users on Ethereum currently hovers between 300,000-400,000, according to Etherscan.

However, Sean Adams noted that 430 million accounts actively use the online payment processor, which means that over 5% of the worlds 8 billion people could theoretically be onboarded onto Ethereum through PayPals new stablecoin.

Martin Koppelmann, the CEO and co-founder of Gnosis, added that by launching PYUSD on Ethereums base layer, Ethereum layer-2s will be able to interact with PYUSD too.

Others, including lawmakers, have seen it as another example of larger institutions embracing crypto, breathing new life into the traditional payments system.

In an Aug. 7 statement, Patrick McHenry, chair of the United States House Committee on Financial Services, said stablecoins like PayPals PYUSD hold promise as a pillar of our 21st century payments system.

However, not everyone is convinced about PayPals new stablecoin.

Several smart contract auditors highlighted that PYUSDs smart contract contains freezefunds and wipefrozenfunds functions, which they claim are textbook examples of centralization attack vectorsin Solidity contracts.

This concern was echoed by cryptocurrency researcher Chris Blec, who believes that PayPal will use the controversial functions where necessary.

Digital asset lawyer Sasha Hodder believes many characteristics of PayPals stablecoin resemble that of a censorship-enabled central bank digital currency. Another smart contract auditor noted that PYUSDs smart contract can be changed by PayPal at any time.

In October, PayPal was slammed for a controversial policy that couldve seen users fined $2,500 for spreading misinformation. The firm later backpedalled, claiming the policy update was published in error.

Related: PayPals crypto holdings increased by 56% in Q1 2023 to nearly $1B

Meanwhile, blockchain engineer Patrick Collins took a slightly more neutral view, suggesting that PayPals PYUSD could have been epic but believes some of the engineering choices were suboptimal such as choosing an outdated version of Solidity to program the contract, making the contract upgradeable and not making it gas efficient.

Sassano also explained in a separate post that while PayPals stablecoin is centralized, Ethereum users are free to choose whether they wish to use it or not.

PayPal said PYUSD will be rolled out within the next few weeks.

ETH is currently priced at $1,825, which is approximately the same price at the time of PayPals announcement about 10 hours ago, according to CoinGecko. Only minor fluctuations have been observed in ETHs price since then.

Magazine: DeFi Dad, Hall of Flame: Ethereum is woefully undervalued but growing more powerful

Read the rest here:

PayPal USD: Boon for Ethereum but not decentralization, says community - Cointelegraph