Archive for the ‘Socialism’ Category

Insensitive and uninformed – The Ellsworth AmericanThe Ellsworth American – The Ellsworth American

Dear Editor:

I try hard to restrain myself from responding to Phil Grants letters, but his latest tirade regarding COVID [COVID science? Dec. 9] is over the top insensitive and uninformed. Just this past week, two long-term residents of Milbridge who he knows died of COVID and there have been more than 750,000 others in the country who have died of COVID.

Is Grant implying that unhealthy children who get COVID are expendable when he says that healthy children need not worry? Should we then separate out the overweight kids, the diabetic kids, any kids who dont seem healthy, and just vaccinate them? Does he imply that the cure is better than the prevention? Why bother with preventative measures like vaccines when there is so much science that promises a cure? And if one has had COVID, why bother with vaccines? All of the assumptions are against the science, and although I doubt that he listens to people like Dr Fauci (sadly, likely because Dr. Faucis a Biden man), Grant begins to sound a lot like his mentor Trump. What educated person would want that comparison?

Finally, Grants letter ends with the dreaded s word that being socialism. Republicans love to throw that out as being the most terrible threat of our time. No letter of Grants could be complete without scaring us about socialism creeping in like a thief in the night. I wonder if he receives Social Security, or if he ever has had to worry about paying medical bills.

Edgar Stanley

Southbridge, Mass. and Milbridge

See the original post here:
Insensitive and uninformed - The Ellsworth AmericanThe Ellsworth American - The Ellsworth American

Uncertain future: workers in the pandemic International Socialism – International Socialism Journal

Production is the essential condition for any functioning human society, and collective human labour the foundation of production. These basic facts are typically buried under an overgrowth of ideology but the Covid-19 pandemic has helped to strip this back, placing work at the centre of contemporary debates.

Conditions within the labour force that once passed unnoticed have suddenly emerged into the light. Addressing the shortage of hauliers in Britain, the Financial Times asked why any young person might wish to work in an industry based around 13 hour days of driving, punctuated by mandatory breaks in inadequate rest stop facilities. Time magazine reported a purported great resignation in the United States, as over four million workers quit their jobs in a single month in autumn 2021. Robert Reich, Bill Clintons former Labour Secretary, suggested that employees dont want to return to backbreaking or boring, low-wage, shit jobs. Workers are burnt out. Theyre fed up. Theyre fried. In the wake of so much hardship and illness and death during the past year, theyre not going to take it any more.

This analysis offers an account of some of the changes to work as the pandemic reaches its two-year mark. It comes with two important caveats. First, this account focuses on Britain and other similar economies. The important topic of work across the Global South is one that will be addressed in future issues. Suffice it to say here, even in countries where the direct health impact of Covid-19 has been more limited due to, for instance, relatively youthful populations, workers have not been spared more than their share of suffering. Economic dislocation in export industries and global supply chains, and declines in areas such as tourism, along with border closures and other restrictions imposed due to the pandemic, have helped drive the first global rise in extreme poverty since 1997.

The second caveat is that the potential impact of the new omicron variant of Covid-19 remained unclear at the time of writing. The failure of governments to control the spread of coronavirus has transformed populations into petri dishes for the creation of new viral strainsa situation exacerbated by the vaccine imperialism of the most powerful states. If new strains such as omicron turn out to be more transmissible, or to have greater capacity to evade existing vaccines, then the already weakening economic recovery could grind to a halt. As International Socialism went to press, Boris Johnsons increasingly crisis-stricken government had just announced new advice for workers to work from home where possible. However, it remained unclear how serious and prolonged a shift this would entail.

We should note, first of all, the peculiarity of the economic crisis accompanying the pandemic. As the first lockdown was imposed, Britain suffered its worst recession in over three centuries. We might envisage two likely outcomes of such a crisis: the failure of large numbers of firms and surging unemployment. The reality has been quite different. The pattern, deepening with each crisis of the 21st century and reaching new levels by 2020-1, has been intensifying action by states and their associated central banks to support firms, whether through direct interventions or measures such as ultra-low interest rates. This creates a situation in which unprofitable zombie firms survive well beyond their natural lifespan. As the pandemic erupted, firm failures fell, only returning to something close to pre-pandemic levels by autumn 2021 (figure 1).

Figure 1: Insolvencies in England and Wales before and during the pandemic

Source: Insolvency Service data.

Not only that, but the furlough scheme implemented by the British state meant a far more muted rise in official unemployment rates than in earlier crises (figure 2). As with similar schemes in France, Germany, Italy and Spain, the British state found itself supporting the income of roughly a third of the workforce, with 11.7 million jobs furloughed at some point in the pandemic. Across high-income countries, employment fell by 18 million between 2019 and 2020, but hours worked fell by the equivalent of 39 million full-time jobs, reflecting the extent to which furlough schemes cushioned labour markets. A similar collapse in working hours took place in Britain, with this figure still well below levels expected from pre-crisis trends (figure 3).

Figure 2: Unemployment rate (16-65, seasonally adjusted) before and during the pandemic

Source: Office for National Statistics data.

Figure 3: Total weekly hours worked (millions) before and during the pandemic

Source: Office for National Statistics data.

In Britain, repeated extensions to the furlough scheme, paid for by expanding state debt, prevented mass unemployment. These measures, along with the vaccine rollout, helps explain Johnsons relative success in riding out the early phases of the pandemic. A cumulative 70 billion (about 2.5 percent of annual GDP) was handed over to 1.3 million employers as part of this scheme.

This kind of intervention meant that the bulk of the labour force in countries such as Britain was divided into four sectionswith workers sometimes moving between groups in the course of the pandemic. First, as noted above, there were those who were placed on temporary furlough. Second, there were those who left the workforce, discussed in more detail below. The third and fourth groups both consisted of people who continued working through the pandemic: respectively, those continuing to travel to their workplace and those for whom some or all their work shifted into their home. Each group was impacted by the pandemic, but not in the same manner.

Those most at risk of death were concentrated in occupations where contact with other workers or the public was expected. As figure 4 shows, workers in caring, leisure and other service occupations, along with those in occupations related to manufacturing, were far more likely to die from causes linked to Covid-19. Factors such as race and classwhich push people into such jobs as well as into overcrowded housing and which lead to poorer overall healthare central to explaining how excess mortality has been distributed across the population.

Figure 4: Deaths involving Covid-19 per 100,000 people between 9 March and 28 December 2020

Source: Office for National Statistics data.

There were lower levels of excess mortality in occupations with less contact with others, particularly where this work was done at home. The extent to which homeworking was used in the pandemic was unprecedented. Numbers travelling to work at least some of the time fell to their lowest ever level, about a third of the workforce, in April 2020. However, by late November 2021, around 71 percent were travelling to work. Most workers were, once more, expected to be present in the workplace.

For those whose work could be carried out remotely, the speed of the transfer of work into the home was striking. Prior to the pandemic just 4.7 percent of employees engaged in home-working: It had taken almost 40 years for home-working to grow by three percentage points, but its prevalence grew eight-fold virtually overnight as people were instructed to work at home if they can because of the pandemic. Around a third of the workforce across Europe and in the US worked from home in early 2020. In some cases, managers had little choice but to make this shift in spite of a negative impact on productivity; in other cases, productivity rose. Overall the changes seem to have averaged out, leading to a broad continuity in the amount of work squeezed out of workers during home-working. This does not take into account other advantages for employers, in particular the potential savings from making employees responsible for supplying office space, equipment and utilities (heating, lighting, internet access) required to do their jobs.

The impact on workers conditions has, unsurprisingly, also been mixed. About half of those who worked at home during the pandemic reported that they would prefer to work mostly or exclusively at home in future. However, this should not be taken as a broad endorsement by workers of the experience. For many, particularly those with caring responsibilities, who are disproportionately women, working from home allows familial and work commitments to be better juggled. Were better public provision made for childcare or if more flexible working patterns were available, this preference could change. Moreover, not all workers can afford the equipment required to work safely and efficiently at home or find the space to do so. Many workers also report feeling drained and isolated or working longer hours than before. The workplace is a site of exploitation, bullying and oppression, but it is also a concentration of collective labour, which makes it a key arena for socialisation and allows workers to express their power. By analogy, the drawing of women out of domestic activities and into waged labour has historically been regarded by Marxists not simply as exposing them to capitalist exploitation, but also as placing them in a world in which their capacity for collective action is enhanced. Although many workers appreciate the flexibility of being able to work from home, a wholesale return of a section of the working class to a more isolated domestic sphere, without freeing them from exploitation, is hardly a panacea.

It is not simply the antipathy of workers towards working in their own homes that is likely to limit the use of remote working post-pandemic. Large amounts of employment continues to rely on access to equipment concentrated in workplaces (most obviously in manufacturing) or the provision of services that require the worker to be present alongside the recipient of those services (for instance, care work, cafes and transportation). Moreover, employers fear that managers may lose their ability to exert direct control over and to supervise remote workers. Even in areas such as finance and business services, an emerging norm at larger firms is for employees to be in the office at least two to four days a week. In cases where there is a shift towards home-working, workers and trade unions will have to formulate new demands to prevent workers subsidising their employers overheads or suffering extended working hours. However, as many areas revert to pre-pandemic patterns, workers will also have to raise demands for flexibility, though on their own terms rather than those of their employers.

Regardless of the eventual redistribution of work between the home and the traditional workplace, the deployment of digital technologies during the pandemic to facilitate the shift reminds us that the use of technology is far from neutral. Such technology does not simply permit changes to the location of work; it is also about measuring and enforcing its intensity and duration. This is a key issue in another form of work much in the spotlight during the pandemic, so-called platform work, mediated by online platforms. Deliveroo and Uber are the most high profile, but this type of work can also include running errands and doing housework along with a large and amorphous category of creative or technical digital tasks. As demand for such services has grown, so has the number of platform workers. One study suggests a modest growth of those obtaining more than half their income from platform work, from roughly 4.1 percent of the workforce in 2019 to around 4.4 percent in 2021.

Although there is little evidence that platform work will displace other forms of employment, we should be aware of the parallels between the use of technology to monitor and enforce work rates in platform work and in non-platform work, particularly in the home. An estimated 9.4 percent of non-platform workers used a specifically designed platform in 2021 to receive notification of the availability of work, with 18.7 percent using a platform to log when work was done.

As noted, there is widespread discussion of a great resignation, focused on the US. Unfortunately, the reality is very far from Reichs hyperbolic claim that workers have declared a national general strike until they get better pay and improved working conditions.

In moments of economic distress, the number voluntarily leaving their jobs tends to fall, as workers seek to hold on to the work they have, while the number involuntarily leaving grows as firms close down or sack workers. These trends were reflected in the US as the pandemic began. Overall job separations rose between 2019 and 2020, driven by employers sacking workers, but the number of voluntary quits fell by 14 percent. The big spike in people voluntarily leaving came in autumn 2021, when the quit rate reached 3 percent in September, the highest figure since collection of this data began in 2000. There were rises in sectors such as manufacturing and education and health services. The most dramatic rise, though, was in leisure and hospitality, in which 6.4 percent of the workforce quit their job. However, we should not overstate the shift. Many of those quitting were people who held back from doing so earlier in the pandemic but felt able to switch jobs as recovery developed. In other words there was a backlog of people who might ordinarily have quit. The total number quitting between March 2020, when the pandemic began to hit, and September 2021, at the height of the great resignation, was 63,873,000. This is slightly lower than the number who quit between March 2018 and September 2019, which stood at 65,856,000.

There has been a small decline in the US labour participation rate, but the most significant reason for this is not younger people dropping out but older people retiring: As of August 2021, there were slightly over 2.4 million excess retirements due to Covid-19more than half of the 4.2 million people who left the labour force from the beginning of the pandemic to the second quarter of 2021. Some of this involved people bringing forward their retirement in fear of contracting Covid-19, but it also reflects the asset prices boom during the recession, due to factors such as quantitative easing, which makes retirement more attractive for some.

Similar patterns hold in Britain. There was a spike in people resigning from their job in autumn 2021, but many simply moved to another similar job. Some 57 percent of those moving jobs remained in the same industry, an increase compared to immediately before the pandemic. The most common reasons for leaving the labour force altogether were long-term illness or retirement.

By autumn 2021, there were record levels of job vacancies, concentrated in areas such as accommodation and food services, manufacturing and construction. However, this sat alongside an overall drop in demand for labour compared to the immediate pre-pandemic period (figure 5). In other words, what is happening here is part of a process of economic rebound from the disruption of the pandemic. Accommodation and food services, in particular, is a highly casualised sector that was largely shut down for long periods in Britain. Even though many of the workers in this sector were furloughed, this does not mean that they returned to the same job when furlough ended. Hence the surge in vacancies now.

Figure 5: Total jobs (1,000s), selected industries, seasonally adjusted

Source: Workforce jobs by industry data, Office for National Statistics

If recovery continues, the whip of economic necessity will likely force workers who have dropped out of the workplace, particularly younger ones, to return. The fact that this adjustment can be prolonged and disruptive demonstrates a point that Marxists have frequently made: labour markets are complex and often recalcitrant institutions. The neoclassical fantasy in which supply and demand neatly adjust to smooth out the requirements of capital is just thata fantasy. However, a long-term shift in the position of labour is unlikely without a higher degree of struggle by workers. Market mechanisms cannot substitute for this.

The ability of some groups of employees to leverage higher wages in the immediate future is unlikely to counteract the other issue facing workers during the recovery from the recessionthe surging cost of living (figure 6).

Figure 6: Consumer price index before and during the pandemic

Source: Monthly Wages and Salaries Survey data from the Office for National Statistics.

Mainstream debate on inflation has polarised between team transitory, who think the inflation is a short-term response to the pandemic, and team permanent, who think that inflation is now more deeply embedded and here for the long term. The debate can run and run, because, as London School of Economics professor Charles Goodhart points out: We have no general theory of inflation. Two established mainstream theoriesthe monetarist theory that inflation is a result of too much money chasing too few goods and the Phillips Curve theory that predicts a trade off between inflation and employmentare both discredited.

Even within Marxist political economy, more work is required to develop a compelling theory of inflation. This is not the place to attempt to provide such a theory. However, broadly speaking, inflation depends on the interrelation between value creation through the expenditure of labour power, the creation of money (primarily through the credit system), and the relationship between capital accumulation and profit rates. Vast amounts of money have been created through quantitative easing since the 2008 recession, and this certainly drove asset price inflation in the financial sector, but we did not witness a surge in the cost of living like the present one. However, if money is injected into the expansion of production but the value of the goods produced and sold is insufficient to mop up all this new money, it is possible for inflation to arise, either through firms raising prices to prop up faltering profitability or as banks continually refinance to allow them to continue their activities through monetary creation. As Anwar Shaikh points out, this is more likely to lead to inflation when the rate of profit is declining but the rate of accumulation has not fallen accordingly, thus sustaining overall demand levels.

However, the pattern in countries such as the US and Britain since the 1990s has tended to be for the rate of accumulation to decline in line with profit rates. Of course, if states embark on a massive programme of investment financed by money created by central banks, there is always the potential for inflation, but so far there is little evidence that this occurring on a sufficient scale. The rise in inflation we are seeing today is more likely a result of the restoration of previous levels of demand in conditions of dislocation and disruption to supply chains and labour markets generated by the pandemic. This has been exacerbated by a lack of investment in oil and gas production, combined with geopolitical tensions, which has pushed up energy prices as demand has rebounded.

If this is correct, inflation is likely to return to lower levels. Indeed, the greater danger may be an overreaction by central banks, in which a rise in interest rates chokes off the delicate recovery altogether.

However, saying that inflation will probably ebb is hardly reassuring to workers. Short term, in this context, can mean months of pain. Workers have to eat and heat their homes now, not in some hypothetical future. Moreover, the rise in the cost of living comes after a decade of stagnating real wages (figure 7). It is absolutely right for workers to demand a pay rise. There have been some important strikes in recent monthsnotably those by university staffand a smattering of victories, particular by workers in transport and logistics, either through threatening or taking industrial action. The recently elected leader of the Unite union, Sharon Graham, is quite right to point out that anything below a 6 percent pay rise is a pay cut. However, much more could be done by the trade union leaders to translate growing discontent among workers into action. In the absence of this, or any lead from the still rightward moving Labour Party leadership of Keir Starmer, socialists will have to do what they can to channel the anger of workers into sustained and collective struggle.

Figure 7: Real Average Weekly Earnings (2015 s)

Source: Office for National Statistics data.

Joseph Choonara is the editor of International Socialism. He is the author of A Readers Guide to Marxs Capital (Bookmarks, 2017) and Unravelling Capitalism: A Guide to Marxist Political Economy (2nd edition: Bookmarks, 2017).

Appiah, Kwame Anthony, 2021, A Tale of Two Pandemics: The True Cost of Covid in the Global South, Guardian (23 November), http://www.theguardian.com/world/2021/nov/23/a-tale-of-two-pandemics-the-true-cost-of-covid-in-the-global-south

Athow, Jonathan, 2021, Far from Average: How Covid-19 has Impacted the Average Weekly Earnings Data, Office for National Statistics blog (15 July), https://blog.ons.gov.uk/2021/07/15/far-from-average-how-covid-19-has-impacted-the-average-weekly-earnings-data

Castro, Miguel Faria e, 2021, The Covid Retirement Boom, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis (15 October), https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/economic-synopses/2021/10/15/the-covid-retirement-boom

Choonara, Joseph, 2018, The Political Economy of a Long Depression, International Socialism 158 (spring), http://isj.org.uk/the-political-economy-of-a-long-depression

Choonara, Joseph, 2021, Vast Impersonal Forces: Biden, State and Capital, International Socialism 171 (summer), http://isj.org.uk/vast-impersonal-forces

Choonara, Joseph, 2022 (forthcoming), The Problem with Precarity: Precarious Employment and Labour Markets, in Joseph Choonara, Annalisa Murgia and Renato Miguel Carmo (eds), Faces of Precarity: Critical Perspectives on Work, Subjectivities and Struggles (Bristol University Press).

Doogan, Kevin, 2009, New Capitalism? The Transformation of Work (Polity).

Felstead, Alan, and Darja Reuschke, 2021 (forthcoming), A Flash in the Pan or a Permanent Change? The Growth of Homeworking during the Pandemic and its Effect on Employee Productivity in the UK, Information Technology & People.

Financial Times Editorial Board, 2021, Making Sense of the Great Resignation, Financial Times (26 November).

Hurley, John, Marta Fana, Drago Adscliei, Giovanna Mazzeo Ortolani, Irene Mandl, Eleonora Peruffo and Carlos Vacas-Soriano, 2021, What Just Happened? Covid-19 Lockdowns and Change in the Labour Market, http://www.eurofound.europa.eu/sites/default/files/ef_publication/field_ef_document/ef21040en.pdf

International Labour Organization, 2021, World Employment and Social Outlook Trends 2021, http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/dgreports/dcomm/publ/documents/publication/wcms_795453.pdf

Rees, Daniel, and Phurichai Rungcharoenkitkul, 2021, BIS Bulletin 48Bottlenecks: Causes and Macroeconomic Implications, Bank for International Settlements (11 November), http://www.bis.org/publ/bisbull48.pdf

Reich, Robert, 2021, Why Yesterdays Bad News about Jobs is Really Good News (9 October), Substack, https://robertreich.substack.com/p/the-general-strike-of-2021

Roberts, Michael, 2020, A Marxist Theory of Inflation, Michael Roberts blog (21 August), https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2020/08/21/a-marxist-theory-of-inflation

Saad-Filho, Alfredo, 2000, Inflation Theory: A Critical Literature Review and a New Research Agenda, Research in Political Economy, volume 18.

Shaikh, Anwar, 1999, Explaining Inflation and Unemployment: An Alternative to Neoliberal Economic Theory, in Andriana Vlachou (ed), Contemporary Economic Theory: Radical Critiques of Neoliberalism (Macmillan).

Spencer, Neil, and Ursula Huws, 2021, Platformisation and the Pandemic: Changes in Workers Experiences of Platform Work in England and Wales, 2016-2021, in Trades Union Congress, Seven Ways Platform Workers Are Fighting Back.

Swindells, Katharine, 2021, What Were Getting Wrong about the Great Resignation, New Statesman (16 November).

Thomas, Daniel, 2021, A Day in the Life of the British Trucker, Financial Times (1 November).

Vesoulis, Abby, 2021, Why Literally Millions of Americans Are Quitting Their Jobs, Time (13 October).

Weldon, Duncan, 2021, We Have No Theory of Inflation, Substack (4 October), https://tinyurl.com/2p8r54hy

Williams, Shannon, and Andrew Kliman, 2014, Falling Profits, Rather than Increasing Financial Investment, Led to Decreasing Rates of Capital Accumulation by American Companies, London School of Economics Phelan US Centre blog (9 October), https://blogs.lse.ac.uk/usappblog/2014/10/09/falling-profits-rather-than-increasing-financial-investment-led-to-decreasing-rates-of-capital-accumulation-by-american-companies

See the article here:
Uncertain future: workers in the pandemic International Socialism - International Socialism Journal

‘Scent of socialism’: Akhilesh Yadav launches ‘Samajwadi …

Branded as Samajwadi Attar, and bottled in red and green glass, the perfume has been made from 22 natural scents. The box comes with a picture of Akhilesh Yadav, with the Samajwadi Partys election symbol on it. (Photo: India Today)

Samajwadi Party (SP) president Akhilesh Yadav has launched a perfume to attract voters to the party in the upcoming Uttar Pradesh Assembly election. Branded as Samajwadi Attar, and bottled in red and green glass, the perfume has been made from 22 natural scents.

The scent will have its magic in 2022 [polls], Akhilesh Yadav said on Tuesday. Uttar Pradesh is due for assembly polls in February-March next year.

The box of the perfume comes with a picture of Akhilesh Yadav, with the Samajwadi Partys election symbol on it. The Samajwadi Party leader from Kannauj and Uttar Pradesh MLC Pushpraj Jain inaugurated the Samajwadi Attar.

Jain said that when people will use the perfume, they would smell "socialism" in it. "Samajwadi perfume will end hate in 2022," Jain said.

This is not the first time the party has launched a perfume. In 2016, Akhilesh Yadav had reportedly launched a range of perfumes named 'Samajwadi Sugandh' to mark four years of his party government in the state.

The perfume was made of four fragrances, with each bottle capturing the fragrance of four different citiesAgra, Lucknow, Varanasi and Kannauj.

READ: Expelled BSP MLAs join SP, Akhilesh Yadav says UP CM may 'change name of cylinders'

ALSO READ: Akhilesh may even convert to get Muslim votes: UP minister

WATCH: Akhilesh slammed for invoking Jinnah: Will it help Samajwadi Party or will it backfire?

Click here for IndiaToday.ins complete coverage of the coronavirus pandemic.

Go here to read the rest:
'Scent of socialism': Akhilesh Yadav launches 'Samajwadi ...

These Three Candidates Worked Together to Bring "Sidewalk Socialism" to Their City Council – In These Times

SOMERVILLE, Mass.Four years ago, Willie Burnley Jr. was forced to move out of his rapidly gentrifying city after alayoff, followed by asteep rent increase. Two years later he had saved enough to return to the city where hed built his post-collegelife.

In summer 2020, Burnley helped found the group Defund Somerville Police (Defund SPD) to combat the citys plan to protect the police budget and cut social servicesincluding the Office of Housing Stability, established the year after Burnleys displacement to help priced-out renters like him. Pressure from Defund SPD, including abike caravan to the homes of city councilmembers, pushed through a7.7% decrease in the citys 2021 police budget, freeing up hundreds of thousands of dollars for housing and foodaid.

On Nov. 2, Burnley, now 27, won aseat on Somerville City Council with aplatform focused on housing and public safety beyond policing. Burnley is no stranger to electoral politics, having worked as afield organizer to re-elect Massachusetts Sens. Elizabeth Warren and Edward Markey, but his own campaign deviated from the standard protocol. It was jointly run with two other first-time candidatesCharlotte Kelly, alongtime education organizer and co-founder of Defund SPD, and Eve Seitchik, aformer co-chair of the local chapter of the Democratic Socialists of America (DSA), which Burnley joined in 2018. The three shared campaign staff and aplatform to create aDSA slate for at-large councilseats.

Working in collaboration was the embodiment of the politics that we wanted to bring to the city council, Burnleysays.

Burnley, Kelly and Seitchik placed second, third and fifth (respectively) among eight at-large candidates, with just the top four candidates winning seats. But come January, Burnley and Kelly will join two DSA-backed incumbents on Somervilles 11-person council, with plans to push apragmatic agenda theyve dubbed sidewalk socialisman homage to the sewer socialists who held office in Milwaukee acentury ago.

On the campaign trail, they connected big-picture priorities with the daily facts of lifelike how aGreen New Deal might expedite sewer upgrades and alleviate flooding. Canvassers also hammered on what Spencer Brown, co-chair of Boston DSA, calls the two Rsrats and rent control. Housing affordability is aperpetual issue, but after hearing complaint after rodent complaint from renters, Kellys campaign released a rat white paper with solutions from experts and community members, such as afree municipal compost program and the expansion of existing rat mitigation programs to includerenters.

Kelly cites that process as an example of how she plans to govern as a movement elected official, to allow people to take ownership over the direction of the policies and structural changes that we need to see, shesays.

Boston-area socialists and progressives also see an opening after the upset victory of Boston Mayor Michelle Wu, who ran on fare-free transit and alocal Green New Deal. She was the sole mayoral candidate to endorse rentcontrol.

To pave the way for sidewalk socialism in Somerville, Boston DSA had hoped to clinch atotal of seven at-large and ward seatsa would-be socialist takeover in the city of 80,000, per aspring 2021 Politico headline. The group also made endorsements in Boston, Cambridge and Medford, deploying some 500 canvassers to knock more than 100,000 doors in four cities. Of 12 endorsed candidates, seven won, most of whom had backing from progressive groups like Our Revolution or Run for Somethingincluding Kendra Hicks, afirst-generation Afro-Latina and self-described socialist who overcame redbaiting and racist attacks to represent Bostons 6thDistrict.

The losses sting, but Brown puts them in context: A few years ago, just getting anyone on acity council would have been adream.

Thats abroad theme for the Left coming out of Election Day, where perhaps the biggest news was insurgent mayoral candidate India Waltons loss in Buffalo, N.Y. But socialists won in at least 23 of the 30 local races where DSAs national organization made endorsements, clinching unlikely victories in cities like St. Petersburg, Fla., and sending multiple members into office in New York City, Ithaca and Rochester, N.Y., andMinneapolis.

Minneapolis also voted down ahigh-profile ballot question that would have allowed the city to replace its police force with adepartment of public safetythough support was highest in the three wards where socialist city council candidates campaigned. But Burnley rejects the narrative that these results represent areferendum on last summers uprising. He cites aTufts University survey showing amajority of Somerville residents think police arent needed in situations involving mental healthcrises.

People know something needs to change. Theres not necessarily aclear consensus on what that [change] needs to be, Burnley says. But thats what organizing isabout.

Burnley adds he didnt shy away from the defund slogan but took the time to talk through adifferent plan for community safetyincluding anew civilian crisis responsesystem.

I cant say Ichanged everyones mind, he says, but thats not the job of acampaign cycle. Thats lifelongwork.

See the original post:
These Three Candidates Worked Together to Bring "Sidewalk Socialism" to Their City Council - In These Times

OPINION: Plymouth and Jamestown rejected socialism, so must we – Westside Eagle Observer

Since 2008 half of America was lured into voting socialist despite the harsh lessons of our socialist beginnings. Plymouth and Jamestown rejected socialism and so must we to provide the level of universal prosperity America has provided its citizens for centuries.

This Thanksgiving Day, we think of the Pilgrims enjoying abundant food, but this was not their true reality. Too few note the difficult times of their first year in 1620 when half died of starvation. Harvests were not bountiful the first year nor the next. Plymouth was beset by laziness and thievery.

William Bradford, the governor of the colony, in his History of Plymouth Plantation, reported that "much was stolen both by night and day" to alleviate the prevailing condition of hunger. The somewhat mythical "feast" of the first Thanksgiving did fill their bellies, he reported, and they were grateful, but abundance had been anything but common. Why? Because they had fallen victim to the socialistic lure of "share the wealth." This disincentivized the productive base of society.

Then suddenly, as though night changed to day, the crop of 1623 was bounteous, and those thereafter as well, and it had nothing to do with the weather. Bradford wrote, "Instead of famine, now God gave them plenty and the face of things was changed, to the rejoicing of the hearts of many, for which they blessed God." He concluded later, "Any general want or famine hath not been amongst them since to this day." They ended universal poverty.

One variable alone made the difference and ended the famine. They abandoned the notion of government (or corporation) owning the means of production and distribution in favor of the individual having property and being responsible to take care of himself. Every family was issued its own land. Before, no one benefited by working for the common store because he received the same compensation as those who did not. After the change, everyone retained the benefits of his labor. Those who chose not to work basically chose also to be poor and the government (corporation) no longer confiscated from those who produced to give to those who did not. There were no government food stamps here.

Ironically, all this could have been avoided had Plymouth consulted history and communicated with their neighboring colony some distance south, which had previously been down the same trail. Jamestown too was first a socialist society where each produced according to his ability and received according to his need, which, of course, affected supply. One cannot divide what does not exist. Our textbooks tell us that only one of twelve survived the first two years for precisely the same reason, starvation. The problem, as noted by Tom Bethel in his work, The Noblest Triumph: Property and Prosperity through the Ages, was identified by an unnamed participant as "want of providence, industrie and government, and not the bareness and defect of the Countrie."

Captain John Smith is credited with having saved the floundering colony by his "no workie, no eatie" government program (the Virginia Company was the government) and was hated for it. Addicted to the promise of getting something for nothing, even if it is always less than promised, the receiving part of the population will always oppose their not getting their "fair share."

Sound familiar? Captain Smith was eventually carted off to England in chains as fast as the parasitic population could do so. Once again, why? Philip A. Bruce, in his Economic History of Virginia in the Seventeenth Century, page 121, called it agricultural socialism. "The settlers did not have even a modified interest in the soil. ... Everything produced by them went into the store, in which they had no proprietorship." When settlers finally were allowed to own their own property and keep what they produced, things changed overnight.

Colony secretary Ralph Hamor wrote of incoming prosperity, beginning in 1614 after ownership of land was allowed: "When our people were fed out of the common store, and labored jointly together, glad was he [who] could slip from his labor, or slumber over his tasks he cared not how, nay, the most honest among them would hardly take so much true pains in a week, as now for themselves they will do in a day, neither cared they for the increase, presuming that however the harvest prospered, the general store must maintain them, so that we reaped not so much corn from the labors of thirty as now three or four do provide for themselves."

This Thanksgiving, let us be grateful for the prosperity that we have -- even the poorest among us. Jamestown and Plymouth set us upon a course that recognized that prosperity requires an incentive to flourish and that the profit motive stimulates industry. We are so grateful that, having recognized the poison of the "share the wealth" philosophy, they purged it from their midst and proceeded to make what eventually became America the most prosperous country on earth.

On January 20, 2021, democratic socialists took over the White House and both branches of Congress. In ten short months of socialist rule, food prices have skyrocketed and shelves are emptying. Once totally energy independent, we now see fuel prices soar and severe shortages are predicted this winter. Joe Biden's prediction of a dark winter appears on the horizon under his administration rather than Trump's. Socialism kills the incentive to produce -- it always has and always will.

Plymouth and Jamestown rejected socialism and so must we. Will we be as smart as they? Let us share this message at the table as we feast upon turkey and pumpkin pie this Thanksgiving Day so that our children will know how prosperity is really produced.

Harold W. Pease, Ph.D., is an expert on the United States Consitution and a syndicated columnist. He has dedicated his career to studying the writings of the Founding Fathers and applying that knowledge to current events. He taught history and political science from this perspective for more than 30 years. To read more of his weekly articles, visit http://www.LibertyUnderFire.org. Opinions expressed are those of the author.

See the original post:
OPINION: Plymouth and Jamestown rejected socialism, so must we - Westside Eagle Observer